Milton Friedman
1912-2006
Milton Friedman was the twentieth
century’s most prominent advocate of free markets. Born in 1912 to
Jewish immigrants in New York City, he attended Rutgers University,
where he earned his B.A. at the age of twenty. He went on to earn his
M.A. from the University of Chicago in 1933 and his Ph.D. from Columbia
University in 1946. In 1951 Friedman received the John Bates Clark Medal
honoring economists under age forty for outstanding achievement. In
1976 he was awarded the Nobel Prize in economics for “his achievements
in the field of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory, and
for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy.” Before
that time he had served as an adviser to President Richard Nixon and
was president of the American Economic Association in 1967. After
retiring from the University of Chicago in 1977, Friedman became a
senior research fellow at the Hoover Institution at Stanford University.
Friedman established himself in 1945 with Income from Independent Professional Practice, coauthored with Simon
Kuznets. In it he argued that state licensing procedures limited entry
into the medical profession, thereby allowing doctors to charge higher
fees than they would be able to do if competition were more open.
His landmark 1957 work, A Theory of the Consumption Function, took on the Keynesian
view that individuals and households adjust their expenditures on
consumption to reflect their current income. Friedman showed that,
instead, people’s annual consumption is a function of their “permanent
income,” a term he introduced as a measure of the average income people
expect over a few years.
In Capitalism and Freedom, Friedman wrote arguably the most
important economics book of the 1960s, making a case for relatively free
markets to a general audience. He argued for, among other things, a
volunteer army, freely floating exchange rates, abolition of licensing
of doctors, a negative income tax, and education
vouchers. (Friedman was a passionate foe of the military draft: he once
stated that the abolition of the draft was almost the only issue on
which he had personally lobbied Congress.) Many of the young people who
read it were encouraged to study economics themselves. His ideas spread
worldwide with Free to Choose (coauthored with his wife, Rose
Friedman), the best-selling nonfiction book of 1980, written to
accompany a TV series on the Public Broadcasting System. This book made
Milton Friedman a household name.
Although much of his trailblazing work was done on price theory—the
theory that explains how prices are determined in individual
markets—Friedman is popularly recognized for monetarism.
Defying Keynes and most of the academic establishment of the time,
Friedman presented evidence to resurrect the quantity theory of
money—the idea that the price level depends on the money supply. In Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money,
published in 1956, Friedman stated that in the long run, increased
monetary growth increases prices but has little or no effect on output.
In the short run, he argued, increases in money supply growth cause
employment and output to increase, and decreases in money supply growth
have the opposite effect.
Friedman’s solution to the problems of inflation
and short-run fluctuations in employment and real GNP was a so-called
money-supply rule. If the Federal Reserve Board were required to
increase the money supply at the same rate as real GNP increased, he
argued, inflation would disappear. Friedman’s monetarism came to the
forefront when, in 1963, he and Anna Schwartz coauthored Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960, which contends that the great depression
was the result of the Federal Reserve’s ill-conceived monetary
policies. Upon receipt of the unpublished manuscript submitted by the
authors, the Federal Reserve Board responded internally with a lengthy
critical review. Such was their agitation that the Fed governors
discontinued their policy of releasing minutes from the board’s meetings
to the public. Additionally, they commissioned a counterhistory to be
written (by Elmus R. Wicker) in the hope of detracting from Monetary History.
Friedman’s book has had a substantial influence on the economics
profession. One measure of that influence is the change in the treatment
of monetary policy given by MIT Keynesian Paul Samuelson in his best-selling textbook, Economics.
In the 1948 edition Samuelson wrote dismissively that “few economists
regard Federal Reserve monetary policy as a panacea for controlling the
business cycle.” But in 1967 Samuelson said that monetary policy had “an
important influence” on total spending. The 1985 edition, coauthored
with Yale’s William Nordhaus, states, “Money is the most powerful and
useful tool that macroeconomic policymakers have,” adding that the Fed
“is the most important factor” in making policy.
Throughout the 1960s, Keynesians—and mainstream economists
generally—had believed that the government faced a stable long-run
trade-off between unemployment and inflation—the so-called phillips curve. In this view the government could, by increasing the demand
for goods and services, permanently reduce unemployment by accepting a
higher inflation rate. But in the late 1960s, Friedman (and Columbia
University’s Edmund Phelps)
challenged this view. Friedman argued that once people adjusted to the
higher inflation rate, unemployment would creep back up. To keep
unemployment permanently lower, he said, would require not just a
higher, but a permanently accelerating inflation rate (see Phillips
curve).
The stagflation of the 1970s—rising inflation combined with rising
unemployment—gave strong evidence for the Friedman-Phelps view and
swayed most economists, including many Keynesians. Again, Samuelson’s
text is a barometer of the change in economists’ thinking. The 1967
edition indicates that policymakers faced a trade-off between inflation
and unemployment. The 1980 edition says there was less of a trade-off in
the long run than in the short run. The 1985 edition says there is no
long-run trade-off.
Selected Works
1945 (with Simon Kuznets). Income from Independent Professional Practice. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
1956. Ed. Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
1962. Price Theory: A Provisional Text. Chicago: Aldine.
1963 (with Anna J. Schwartz). A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
1972. An Economist’s Protest: Columns on Political Economy. Glen Ridge, N.J.: Thomas Horton and Daughters.
1980 (with Rose Friedman). Free to Choose. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
No comments:
Post a Comment