1766-1834
Malthus was interested in everything about populations.
He accumulated figures on births, deaths, age of marriage and
childbearing, and economic factors contributing to longevity. His main
contribution was to highlight the relationship between food supply and
population. Humans do not overpopulate to the point of starvation, he
contended, only because people change their behavior in the face of economic incentives.
Noting that while food production tends to increase
arithmetically, population tends to increase naturally at a (faster)
geometric rate, Malthus argued that it is no surprise that people thus choose
to reduce (or “check”) population growth. People can increase food
production, Malthus thought, only by slow, difficult methods such as
reclaiming unused land or intensive farming; but they can check
population growth more effectively by marrying late, using
contraceptives, emigrating, or, in more extreme circumstances, resorting
to reduced health care,
tolerating vicious social diseases or impoverished living conditions,
warfare, or even infanticide. Malthus was fascinated not with the
inevitability of human demise, but with why humans do not die off in the face of such overwhelming odds. As an economist, he studied responses to incentives.
Malthus is arguably the most misunderstood and
misrepresented economist of all time. The adjective “Malthusian” is used
today to describe a pessimistic prediction of the lock-step demise of a
humanity doomed to starvation via overpopulation. When his hypothesis
was first stated in his best-selling An Essay on the Principle of Population
(1798), the uproar it caused among noneconomists overshadowed the
instant respect it inspired among his fellow economists. So irrefutable
and simple was his illustrative side-by-side comparison of an arithmetic
and a geometric series—food increases more slowly than population—that
it was often taken out of context and highlighted as his main
observation. The observation is, indeed, so stark that it is still easy
to lose sight of Malthus’s actual conclusion: that because humans have not all starved, economic choices must be at work, and it is the job of an economist to study those choices.
Malthus addressed many other issues. His Principles of Political Economy (1820) was the first text to describe a demand schedule as separate from the quantity demanded at a given price. His exposition of demand curves clarified the debate on Say’s
law and gluts (to which he objected in the long run on the grounds that
markets self-adjust). His work centered on contrasting the long run, as
exemplified by population growth, with the short run, reflected by
cyclical events such as those affecting agriculture. Writing before the industrial revolution,
Malthus did not fully appreciate the impact of technology (i.e.,
pesticides, refrigeration, mechanized farm equipment, and increased crop
yields) on food production.
Malthus died in 1834, before seeing economics characterized
as the “dismal science.” That phrase, coined by Thomas Carlyle in 1849
to demean John Stuart Mill, is often erroneously thought to refer to Malthus’s contributions to the economics of population growth.
Selected Works
1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. 1st ed. 1798, online at the Library of Economics and Liberty, http://www.econlib.org/library/Malthus/malPop.html; 6th ed. 1826, online at the Library of Economics and Liberty, http://www.econlib.org/library/Malthus/malPlong.html.
1811. “Pamphlets on the Bullion Question.” Edinburgh Review 18 (August): 448–470.
1820. The Principles of Political Economy Considered with a View to Their Practical Applications. London: John Murray.
No comments:
Post a Comment